Foreword |
|
v | |
Introduction |
|
1 | (1) |
|
Ethical Economy and Political Economy |
|
|
1 | (4) |
|
Ethical Economy as Theory of the Ethical Presuppositions of the Economy and Economic Ethics |
|
|
3 | (1) |
|
Ethical Economy as Economic Theory of the Ethical or Ethics Oriented toward Economics |
|
|
3 | (1) |
|
Ethical Economy as Substantive Theory of Goods and Cultural Economics |
|
|
4 | (1) |
|
Why the Interest in Economic Ethics Today? |
|
|
5 | (7) |
|
Increasing Side Effects of Economic Activity |
|
|
6 | (2) |
|
Rediscovery of the Human Person |
|
|
8 | (1) |
|
Normative Penetration of the Economy as Complement of its Differentiation |
|
|
9 | (3) |
|
Overview of the Structure of the Book |
|
|
12 | (1) |
|
Missing Mediation of Economics and Ethics in Modernity -- Ethical Economy as Post-Modern Economics |
|
|
13 | (4) |
|
Economics, Ethics, and Religion: Positive Theory of the Coordination of Self-Interested Actions |
|
|
17 | (21) |
|
Internalization of Side Effects and Inclusion of Persons Affected as Criteria of Social Coordination |
|
|
17 | (1) |
|
Private Vices - Public Benefits: The Good as Side Effect |
|
|
18 | (2) |
|
|
20 | (6) |
|
Ethics as Corrective for Economic Failure |
|
|
26 | (5) |
|
Religion as Corrective for Ethical Failure |
|
|
31 | (3) |
|
Self-Interest, Corporate Ethics, and Employee Motivation |
|
|
34 | (4) |
|
Economics and Ethics I: Formal Ethics |
|
|
38 | (43) |
|
Ethics and Economics: Global and Local Maximization |
|
|
39 | (7) |
|
Unifying Universalization and Exception: Ethics and Religion |
|
|
46 | (2) |
|
Economic, Ethical, and Religious Rationality: Extending the Limits of the Self |
|
|
48 | (6) |
|
Love of Self -- Love of God -- Love of Neighbor: Augustine's Understanding of the Transformations and Coordinations of Self-Interest |
|
|
49 | (2) |
|
Economization of Ethics and Religion? |
|
|
51 | (3) |
|
Rationality and Coordination |
|
|
54 | (5) |
|
The A Priori Nature of the Principle of Rationality |
|
|
54 | (3) |
|
Formal Rationality and Non-Formal, Substantive Rationality |
|
|
57 | (2) |
|
Ethics as Form of Social Coordination |
|
|
59 | (13) |
|
Convergence of Ethical Universalization and Market Coordination in the Formal Nature of their Laws |
|
|
60 | (4) |
|
Kantian Ethics as the Solution to the Prisoner's Dilemma |
|
|
64 | (3) |
|
Formal Ethics as Internal Pre-Coordination of the Economic Coordination of the Price System |
|
|
67 | (2) |
|
Deepening Social Coordination by Ethics |
|
|
69 | (1) |
|
Ethics as the Reduction of Uncertainty about the Decision Behavior of Other Persons and its Composition into Patterns of Social Interaction |
|
|
70 | (2) |
|
Ethics and Religion as Ways of Increasing Economic Rationality and Coordination |
|
|
72 | (6) |
|
Ethics as the Ability to Endure the Consequences of One's Own Actions |
|
|
75 | (2) |
|
Ethics and Economics in the View of Interpretive Sociology |
|
|
77 | (1) |
|
Formality and Materiality |
|
|
78 | (3) |
|
Economics and Ethics II: Substantive Ethics |
|
|
81 | (31) |
|
Ethical and Economic Theories of Goods |
|
|
82 | (5) |
|
The Theory of the Highest Good |
|
|
83 | (2) |
|
Scheler's Substantive Ethics of Values |
|
|
85 | (2) |
|
Experiencing Values and Understanding Cultural Meaning |
|
|
87 | (2) |
|
Side Effects between Experiences and Value Convictions, ``Is'' and ``Ought'' |
|
|
89 | (2) |
|
Substantive Value-Qualities and Degrees of the Publicness of Goods |
|
|
91 | (5) |
|
Ethics as Theory of Virtues |
|
|
96 | (8) |
|
The Interchangeability of Means and Ends and the Economics of Sublimation |
|
|
98 | (3) |
|
Proper Conduct, or Appropriateness to the Nature of the Matter, and Justice as Virtue |
|
|
101 | (3) |
|
The Unity of Ethics as the Theory of Duty, of Virtue, and of the Good... |
|
|
104 | (4) |
|
Everything Worth Doing Is Worth Doing Well, or The Good as Perfection |
|
|
108 | (4) |
|
|
112 | (11) |
|
Cultural Economics and the Cultural Philosophy of the Economy |
|
|
112 | (2) |
|
The Culture of Production |
|
|
114 | (1) |
|
The Culture of Consumption |
|
|
115 | (2) |
|
Technological Progress and Transformations in the Meaning of Work in Society |
|
|
117 | (4) |
|
|
121 | (2) |
|
Economics, Ethics, and Decision Theory: The Problem of Controlling Side Effects |
|
|
123 | (19) |
|
The Law of Intended Side Effects in the Firm |
|
|
125 | (3) |
|
Side Effects as Decision Problem |
|
|
128 | (14) |
|
Uncertainty about the Consequences of Actions in Ethics, Economics, and Decision Theory |
|
|
129 | (2) |
|
|
131 | (3) |
|
Criticisms of Probabilistic Decision Calculi |
|
|
134 | (3) |
|
The Principle of Double Effect |
|
|
137 | (5) |
|
|
142 | (27) |
|
Intentional or Natural-Scientific Ontology of the Economy? |
|
|
143 | (6) |
|
The Inconceivability of an Objective General Equilibrium and Universal Mechanism |
|
|
149 | (2) |
|
The Market Economy as Teleological Mechanism |
|
|
151 | (2) |
|
General Equilibrium as Transcendental Ideal |
|
|
153 | (4) |
|
Poietic Imagination of New Possibilities in the Market Process |
|
|
157 | (2) |
|
The Market as Social Discourse and Process of Entelechial Coordination |
|
|
159 | (1) |
|
Not Value Subjectivism, but Subjective Value-Realization |
|
|
160 | (4) |
|
Ethical Economy or Subjective Economics as General Theory of Human Action? |
|
|
164 | (5) |
|
Economic Ethics in the Market Economy |
|
|
169 | (15) |
|
Does the ``Mechanism of Competition'' Make Ethics Superfluous? |
|
|
169 | (5) |
|
Morality and Advantage: The Costs of Economic Ethics |
|
|
174 | (4) |
|
|
178 | (3) |
|
Proper Conduct and Appropriateness to the Nature of the Subject Matter in Question |
|
|
181 | (3) |
|
|
184 | (27) |
|
Commutative Justice as Appropriateness to the Nature of the Matter of Exchange: The Equivalence Principle |
|
|
184 | (1) |
|
How Do We Determine What Each Person is Entitled to in Exchange? |
|
|
185 | (20) |
|
Joining the Prevailing Price by the Actual Contract Price |
|
|
186 | (7) |
|
Appropriateness to the Nature of the Item Exchanged: No Exchange of Sham Goods |
|
|
193 | (2) |
|
Mutually-Advantageous Exchange: Neither Party Suffers a Loss of Net Wealth |
|
|
195 | (2) |
|
Commutative Justice as Virtue |
|
|
197 | (5) |
|
The Unavoidability of the Question of Justice |
|
|
202 | (3) |
|
What Is the Basis of the Obligation to Give Each Person What Is His or Hers in Exchange? |
|
|
205 | (6) |
|
|
211 | (33) |
|
Preliminary Historical Remark: The Significance of Early-Modern, Probabilistic Just Price Theory |
|
|
212 | (3) |
|
Natural Law and Forces of Nature in the Legitimation of the Price System |
|
|
215 | (3) |
|
What Distinguishes the Price System from Other Forms of Price Determination? |
|
|
218 | (1) |
|
Formal and Non-Formal or Substantive Conditions of Price Justice |
|
|
219 | (8) |
|
Unification of Procedural and Structural Justice |
|
|
223 | (2) |
|
Allocation and Distribution |
|
|
225 | (2) |
|
International Price Justice |
|
|
227 | (2) |
|
Justice as Satisfying a Criterion or as a Synopsis of Several Criteria? |
|
|
229 | (12) |
|
Rawls' Criterion of a Veil of Ignorance |
|
|
230 | (1) |
|
The Utilitarian Criterion of Total-Utility Maximization |
|
|
231 | (4) |
|
|
235 | (2) |
|
Nozick's Criterion of the Justified Claim |
|
|
237 | (1) |
|
Unification of Procedural and End-State Criteria |
|
|
238 | (3) |
|
Justice in Interaction with Nature |
|
|
241 | (3) |
Conclusion: Morality and Efficiency |
|
244 | (3) |
Bibliography |
|
247 | (19) |
Index of Persons |
|
266 | (5) |
Index of Subjects |
|
271 | |